Индексы многомерной бедности для детей на основе обследований домохозяйств: уроки и дальнейшие действия 1

ВАК
inLibrary
Google Scholar
Выпуск:
CC BY f
264-293
21
4
Поделиться
Эванс, М., Ханджиоглу, А., & Абдуразаков, А. (2017). Индексы многомерной бедности для детей на основе обследований домохозяйств: уроки и дальнейшие действия 1. Экономика и инновационные технологии, (6), 264–293. извлечено от https://inlibrary.uz/index.php/economics_and_innovative/article/view/9578
Crossref
Сrossref
Scopus
Scopus

Аннотация

В данной статье рассматриваются подходы, используемые для измерения детской многомерной бедности (МДБ) в развивающихся странах: метод Алкира-Фостера и метод «CC» на примере индексов бедности ЮНИСЕФ, основанных на методологиях Gordon et al и De Neubourg et al. Обсуждение начинается с микроданных обследований, широко используемых для этих индексов, кластерных обследований по многим показателям (MICS) и демографических и медицинских обследований (DHS), и вытекающих из этого ограничений данных по индексам для измерения и охвата MDP для детей. Выявлены два важных ограничения, влияющих на измерение MDP по обоим индексам: а) включение показателей как на уровне домохозяйств, так и на индивидуальном уровне, б) возрастная специфика индивидуальных показателей для детей и представленность в данных обследования. Анализ рассматривает основные различия между двумя методологиями в два этапа. Во-первых, используя моделирование методом Монте-Карло гипотетических данных, мы рассматриваем различия в свойствах измерения, возникающие в результате аксиоматического построения индексов, и эффекты, которые «домашние и индивидуальные» смешанные данные уровня и «возрастная специфика» оказывают на такие аксиоматические свойства. Во-вторых, мы используем гармонизированные данные DHS из трех стран, чтобы изучить, как эти аксиоматические различия в свойствах измерения влияют на распространенность MDP внутри стран и между ними, а также на способность индексов отслеживать изменения в распространенности MDP. Документ завершается рассмотрением результатов анализа и тем, как их можно использовать в будущем при сборе и анализе данных обследования для оценки ППР для детей в задачах и показателях Целей в области устойчивого развития, с особым упором на программу обследования MICS.

Похожие статьи


background image

“Иқтисодиёт ва инновацион технологиялар” илмий электрон журнали. № 6, ноябрь-декабрь, 2017 йил

1

№ 6, 2017

www.iqtisodiyot.uz

Multi-dimensional Poverty Indices for Children from Household Surveys:

Lessons and ways forward

1

Martin C Evans

Attila Hancioglu

Akmal Abdurazakov

Draft Working Paper Version

Not for quotation – circulate with care

Abstract:

This paper considers approaches used to measure child multi-

dimensional poverty (MDP) in the developing world: the Alkire-Foster method and
the ‘CC’ method as exemplified by UNICEF poverty indices based on methodologies
by Gordon et al and De Neubourg et al. Discussion begins with survey micro-data
extensively used for these indices, the Multiple Indicator Cluster Surveys (MICS) and
the Demographic and Health Surveys (DHS), and the resulting data constraints on
indices for measurement and coverage of MDP for children. Two important
constraints are identified as affecting measurement of MDP across both indices: a)
the inclusion of both household level and individual level indicators, b) the age-
specificity of individual indicators for children and representation in survey
data. Analysis considers the underlying differences between the two methodologies in
two stages. First, using Monte Carlo simulations of hypothetical data we consider the
differences in measurement properties that arise from axiomatic construction of
indices, and the effects that ‘household and individual’ mixed level data and ‘age
specificity’ have on such axiomatic properties. Second, we use harmonized DHS data
from three countries to examine how those axiomatic differences in measurement
properties affect MDP prevalence within and across countries, and the ability of
indices to monitor changes in MDP prevalence. The paper concludes by considering
the findings from the analysis and how they could be taken forward in the future
collection and analysis of survey data for estimating MDP for children in Sustainable
Development Goals targets and indicators, with particular reference to the MICS
survey programme.

Keywords:

Child poverty; MICS; DHS

1

<Acknowledgements here >.


background image

“Иқтисодиёт ва инновацион технологиялар” илмий электрон журнали. № 6, ноябрь-декабрь, 2017 йил

2

№ 6, 2017

www.iqtisodiyot.uz

Introduction

The inclusion of multi-dimensional poverty in the Sustainable Development

Goals (SDGs) in 2015 was a long-awaited recognition of its importance and
relevance, but has raised new, potentially exacting, requirement on measurement.
The SDGs also prioritise children within poverty measurement making child multi-
dimensional poverty a key area for SDG goals and targets. While children’s multi-
dimensional poverty indices may have been primarily constructed for advocacy
purposes prior to the SDGs, they now have to perform as poverty measurement tools
and thus have clear cardinal and scalar properties, to set robust baselines, and be able
to capture changes in poverty over time to monitor SDG targets. This paper
considers the underlying methodologies of approaches that are in place to meet this
challenge.

Measurement of multi-dimensional poverty has grown rapidly since UNICEF’s

ground-breaking 2003 report on global multi-dimensional poverty for children
(Gordon et al 2003). Other methods appeared, most notably the adoption by Human
Development Report of the Multidimensional Poverty Index (MPI) using Alkire-
Foster methodology in 2010 (Alkire & Foster 2011) for the Human Development
Report (UNDP 2010). The A-F methodology (but not MPI) has now also been
adopted by the World Bank implementing an index to meet the recommendation of
the ‘Atkinson’ report (Commission on Global Poverty 2017). In Europe, Eurostat
have developed multiple material deprivation measures that also consider non-
monetary measures of poverty in a multi-dimensional approach (Eurostat 2015).

The literature on multidimensional indices and measurement has also expanded

exponentially in the past 10-15 years across a wide set of disciplinary and technical
approaches: from indices developed in theoretical terms using mathematical and
econometric specifications in economics journals to descriptive and normative studies
using qualitative and quantitative data in policy and children’s journals. However, on
characteristic of the literature is that multi-dimensional child poverty has been
dominated by the latter approaches, and thus has mostly avoided the technical
scrutiny of econometricians who dominate the former.

Our paper proceeds as follows. The remainder of this introductory section

outlines the household survey data used for the indices then the multi-dimensional
index methodologies that we compare. The analytical part of the paper follows in
two parts: Part 1 considers ‘laboratory’ tests of the main indices in comparison to a
simple ‘sum-count’ index as a benchmark; Part 2 considers the indices as
implemented in actual household survey data in three countries to assess how far the
‘laboratory’ findings are present in real data. The paper then reviews its findings and
makes some hesitant conclusions about both methodology and data.

Household Survey Data

We concentrate on the main sources of survey data that are currently feeding

into large scale multi-dimensional child poverty measurement: USAID-supported
Demographic and Health Surveys (DHS) and the UNICEF-supported Multiple
Indicator Cluster Surveys (MICS). Current indices are constructed on data from
these surveys undertaken before 2015, and thus not reflecting the SDG agenda. Both
the MICS and DHS programmes were initiated prior to the Millennium Development


background image

“Иқтисодиёт ва инновацион технологиялар” илмий электрон журнали. № 6, ноябрь-декабрь, 2017 йил

3

№ 6, 2017

www.iqtisodiyot.uz

Goals, in 1995 and 1984, respectively (Hancioglu and Arnold, 2013). However, both
programmes evolved to include all relevant MDG indicators in time, leading to the
reporting of many MDG indicators based on results of MICS and DHS surveys for
the majority of low and middle income countries. IN terms of content and household
survey methodology, the two programmes display a large amount of similarities, and
collaborate closely and work through interagency processes in an effort to harmonize
survey tools and ensure comparability to the extent possible. However, there are also
key differences between the two programmes, some of which are obvious differences
and many subtle. In most cases, comparability of data from these two survey
programmes is not compromised by methodological differences, which means that
analysts can use data from both surveys to track trends in key indicators, especially
since many countries regularly conduct both surveys, usually with reasonable
intervals.

Both survey programmes offer a large amount of data that is or can potentially

be used for multi-dimensional poverty analysis. The DHS programme focuses on data
on health and population trends, with emphasis on fertility, family planning,
mortality, reproductive health, child health, gender-related issues such as domestic
violence, HIV/AIDS, malaria, and nutrition. MICS surveys provide key information
on mortality, health, nutrition, education, HIV/AIDS, and child protection for use in
programme decision making, advocacy, and national and global reporting. Both
surveys are implemented by government agencies – in the case of MICS, almost all
MICS surveys are conducted and owned by National Statistics Offices. MICS and
DHS survey programmes regularly update and modify the contents of their
questionnaires and frequently lead methodological developments in measurement of
indicators in household surveys. Currently, both programmes are close to completion
of inclusion of all relevant SDG indicators – both covering more than 30 SDG
indicators, mostly overlapping.

One of the key differences between the two survey programmes is the way that

the child population is covered. The MICS programme has traditionally included a
separate under-5 questionnaire, administered to mothers, or in the absence of mothers
from the household list, to caretakers, which ensures that in the presence of
significant orphanhood and fostering, all children are covered by the survey. MICS
has recently added a separate 5-17 Children’s Questionnaire, again administered to
mothers and caretakers with the same principle of full coverage in mind. The DHS
programme also targets to cover all children; however, DHS does not include a
separate questionnaire for children and obtains much of the information on children
from their biological mothers.

Two key aspects of MICS and DHS data influence the performance of multi-

dimensional poverty indices in practice:

Surveys collect data at two levels:

individual and household

. Surveys

collect common information on household and community level services – such as
water, sanitation, and on household level resources – such as assets, the material
construction of the home and demographic make-up of the household. Data on
health, education and other areas of child and maternal well-being are collected at
individual level – either from adult respondents or directly from child level


background image

“Иқтисодиёт ва инновацион технологиялар” илмий электрон журнали. № 6, ноябрь-декабрь, 2017 йил

4

№ 6, 2017

www.iqtisodiyot.uz

observations – e.g. anthropometrics. This means that many indicators of child
poverty are clustered at the household level – all children are poor under that
indicator if it is fulfilled at the household level, while there will be observed variance
between children within households for child level data. Such clustering has serious
outcomes for measuring differences at the individual level and can severely limit
interpretations of gender, birth order or other individual level difference when both
levels of indicators are joined into the same index.

Surveys collect data for

age-specific profiles at the individual level

. Data on

children is collected specifically for certain age-related risk groups: for instance,
detailed anthropometric data is only collected for those aged less than 60 months.
This means that indicators for ‘nutrition’, health, education and other crucial areas of
child poverty and wellbeing are not available for all ages of children. This creates
‘censored’ data at the individual level, and further limits the assessment of individual
level differences in children when such censored data is joined to household level
data in indices – differences from age-composition of individual children now
reinforce difficulty in measuring individual level differences that may already be
obscured by clustering in households. The issue of age or population specific data
and its effect on multi-dimensional indices was discussed at length by Dotter and
Klasen (2015) and led to revisions of UNDP’s MPI (Kovasevic and Calderon 2016)

The DHS and MICS programmes were never set up to ensure that indicators

are present in sufficient numbers for household and individual indicators, and
certainly not with the intention of capturing multi-dimensional poverty from an
individual perspective, in the way that child multi-dimensional poverty is now
defined. Since both programmes were designed before the advent of
multidimensional poverty analysis and were based on key indicators in the sectors of
concern, limitations as described above are natural. However, both surveys have been
extensively used for such multi-dimensional analysis, and a recent development is the
inclusion of derived multi-dimensional poverty indicators in the list of indicators of
the MICS programme, which means that (1) the survey reports will be regularly
producing estimates of multi-dimensional poverty, (2) the programme is likely to
align closely to current and future developments in multi-dimensional poverty
analysis and methodology

Multidimensional Poverty Indices

We limit our review to ‘counting indices’ drawn from DHS and MICS survey

data. In these indicators are arithmetically summed according to a range of different
weighting and aggregation assumptions. In its simplest form, a set of indicators for a
counting index can be the sum of each indicator expressed in binary form. Thus, an
index from 10 indicators, in this simple form, is the ‘sum count’ of deprivation
indicators each child has, from zero to 10.

The assignment of indicators into dimensions is where methodologies differ,

and differences arise in both the allocation of weights to indicators and/or dimensions
and the approach to assigning indicators to and within dimensions. We consider two
approaches

A-F methodology (hereinafter ‘A-F’) is an index formed from a sum of

binary indicators with no axiomatic adoption of weighting protocol. In applied


background image

“Иқтисодиёт ва инновацион технологиялар” илмий электрон журнали. № 6, ноябрь-декабрь, 2017 йил

5

№ 6, 2017

www.iqtisodiyot.uz

practice, indicator level weights are determined according the assignment of
dimensions that classify indicators. Using such an approach, the sum of dimensions
and indicators will be 1, but each indicator can be weighted independently or per
share allotted to the dimension of which it is a part. In the most well know precedent,
the global MPI, three dimensions were set to reflect the three dimensions of UNDP’s
Human Development Index (health, education and living standards) each having
equal weight of 1/3. Education and health dimensions had two indicators each with
resulting weights of 1/6; the ‘Living Standards’ dimension had 6 indicators, resulting
in indicators weights of 1/18. But, while the MPI dominates discussion,

it should be

considered a variant of A-F, not its essential representation.

For instance, Vietnam’s

Multidimensional Poverty measure, called MDP, (MOLISA 2016) has 5 dimensions
and 10 indicators, thus each indicator has a weight of 1/10 and is an exact replication
of the simple ‘sum-count’ index discussed earlier. Indeed, national ‘MPIs’ adopted
by governments across the developing world, differ from the global version in many
ways.

The setting of indicator cut-offs and poverty thresholds for the resulting index

score leads to a poverty A-F headcount measure index and is accompanied by poverty
metrics for ‘intensity’ and ‘adjusted headcount’ measures that allow a complete
reconciliation of poverty measurement to the Foster, Greer Thorbecke (reference)
standards for monetary poverty, and thus to intensity and ‘poverty gaps and to most
of the axiomatic requirement of poverty measurement established in the poverty
literature (Alkire S et al 2015).

Children’s multi-dimensional poverty can be captured by disaggregating

household level MPI by age– as most recently done at the global level for the first
time (Alkire et al 2017). But specific child level A-F measures also exist and, while
established early in the literature (Roche 2013), have been much later arriving in
practice in national poverty profiles. Bhutan was the first country to officially adopt
an individual level ‘child MPI’ (Alkire et al 2016) and examples are currently
underway in Vietnam, Maldives, Afghanistan, Malaysia, and other countries.

Categorical Counting (hereinafter ‘CC’). This term is ours and refers to a

number of indices that use a normative ‘rights based approach.

2

The crucial

arithmetic differences to both A-F and the ‘sum-count’ approaches are four-fold

o

The

dimensions are counted

to produce the index score

o

Aggregation of indictors into dimensions uses a ‘Boolean’ logic of the

‘union approach’ meaning that the dimensional binary score is one if

any

of the

indicators in that dimension is positive, or is zero if not one of them is positive.

o

There is no necessity for consistent number of indicators per dimension.

Some dimensions contain a single indicator (often ‘sanitation’ and ‘water’
dimensions in practice), while others can contain 2 or more indicators.

o

It is axiomatic that

each dimension has equal weight

arising from a

normative rights-based assertion used in the approach

2

Another term could be ‘dimensional counting’ but with A-F decomposition often producing results by dimension, we

consider our term less ambiguous.


background image

“Иқтисодиёт ва инновацион технологиялар” илмий электрон журнали. № 6, ноябрь-декабрь, 2017 йил

6

№ 6, 2017

www.iqtisodiyot.uz

These indices are of longer standing – starting with Gordon et al’s 2003 global

child poverty profile (op-cit) and subsequent UNICEF global poverty and disparities
profiles in around 50 countries, and a specific version of that index for Latin America
(CEPAL/UNCEF 2010, 2012). More recently, Multiple Overlapping Deprivation
Analysis (MODA) was developed using a similar approach (De Neuburgh et al 2013)

The Analysis

There is a small literature that directly compares these indices in practice. For

instance, a comparison of individual level MODA indices compared to MPI
household level indices for the same country (ies) (Calderon & Evans 2015, OoR
paper). While these studies find differences in the level and composition of poverty,
such differences can be difficult to interpret if it is not clear how they arise: from the
underlying methodology, or from the construction in survey data (through use of
different indicators, difference in the construction of similar indicators, or from
underlying data cleaning work such as trimming of data for outliers, etc.). The MPI’s
early years was characterized by criticism of multi-dimensional assumptions and
measurement outcomes from poverty economists established in the monetary
approach (Ravallion 2011 and others). Over time a much larger analytical literature
has arisen on the A-F approach and its comparison to statistical and econometric
measurement practice of poverty in general. For instance, tests of robustness and
sensitivity for MPI have been undertaken (Alkire 2014, for instance), alternative
theoretical measurement approaches compared (Rippin 2010 and others). Technical
evaluation of the CC approach has been minimal by comparison.

Our primary research questions go back to the applied question of poverty

measurement for the SDGs: How do the A-F and CC approaches perform in terms
of three clear questions:

How do they differ in cardinal and scalar properties?

How do they set robust baselines?

How do they asses if poverty is changing over time to meet SDG targets?

Our approach is to consider the properties that arise from axiomatic

measurement principles in the first instance and then to assess how such identified
properties affect performance in actual household survey data. We do not start with
an algebraic proof for several reasons. First, we want to reach a wide audience that is
more ‘practice based’ than the readership of highly technical econometric,
mathematical and statistical journals. Second, algebra can sometimes be a ‘black box’
that hides uncertainty and assumptions. When considering counting indices, the
Greek symbol sigma

Ʃ

may represent a cumulative sum of non-consistent

components, and thus obscure differences between ordinal, categorical and cardinal
interpretations. Third, our worked examples from ‘laboratory data’ benefit from and
include the outcomes of a ‘trial and error’ process in some instances. Indeed, a lesson
from our work is that demonstrating ex-ante theoretical measurement problems in the
lab can identify unforeseen measurement properties. We end our analysis by moving
from laboratory data to implement indices using real survey data and thus to move
from discussions of pure measurement ‘theory’ into applied ‘practice’. We test real
micro-survey data from three countries to see if the findings from laboratory tests are
validated.


background image

“Иқтисодиёт ва инновацион технологиялар” илмий электрон журнали. № 6, ноябрь-декабрь, 2017 йил

7

№ 6, 2017

www.iqtisodiyot.uz

Our motivation is to beyond simple descriptive comparisons of indices already

in place and concentrate on underlying methodology and its applied outcomes for
data and poverty profiles. But the potential lure of specific brands of indices
(MODA, MPI) is strong and thus we avoid ‘brand’ comparisons of particular named
indices but instead concentrate on the underlying measurement approaches and their
assumptions. Our comparisons and review are of A-F, CC methodologies and
generalizable properties of them. We recognize the investments that have gone into
named indices but our analysis is of A-F and CC approaches, and not of the indices
that spring from them: MODA, MPI, CEPAL/UNICEF etc.

Part 1:
Tests Using Laboratory Data

We construct laboratory data of 10,000 hypothetical observations with 10 non-

specified binary indicators for each observation. We randomly (coin-flip) allocate
ones and zero scores to each indicator. This means that in our first set of estimates all
indicators are independent of each other and there is, by definition, no correlation, an
assumption that we change later when we reflect further in our sensitivity and
monotonicity analysis. For the random data, we make comparisons between indices
from 100 Monte Carlo trials of coin-flip random allocation to provide robust
estimates at 99.9 percent level. This provides us a baseline distribution and result for
a mean score of 0.5 across the 10 indicators against which to compare index
performance.

We have three test versions of indices:

A-F index. Our test index uses the same weights as those in the global MPI

discussed earlier – reflecting noth the most well-known version of their methodology
and the individual level MPI index demonstrated by Klasen and Lahoti (2016).

o

Four of the ten indicators have weights of 1/6 and

o

six indicators have weights of 1/18.

The CC index. Our test index uses weights and approaches from the applied

literature (Gordon et al 2003 and De Neuburg et al 2013).

o

Five dimensions:

three dimensions are populated by 2 indicators in ‘union approach’

one dimension has 3 indicators in union approach and

one dimension has just one indicator.

The ‘Sum-Count’ index. This is for comparison and baselining purposes.

o

Ten indicators each with equal weight of 0.1.

Tests for Index Scales and Baselines

Figure 1 shows the results. Figure 1 a) shows the ‘sum count’ benchmark

index, which, definition and by construction, produces a mean and median score of
0.5. It has a normal distribution that has 11 scalar increments set at 0.1 apart between
zero and one, and that has and a standard deviation of 0.16. These are bench-test
reference results against which to compare the other indices.

Figure 1b) shows the A-F index also results in a bell curve distribution, (but

Shapiro-Wilk tests do

not confirm

it is a normal distribution) with 18 equal


background image

“Иқтисодиёт ва инновацион технологиялар” илмий электрон журнали. № 6, ноябрь-декабрь, 2017 йил

8

№ 6, 2017

www.iqtisodiyot.uz

increments of 0.566 (the value of the smallest weight) between 0 and 1. Having index
weights smaller than 1/10 results in a more granular distribution compared to the
‘sum count’ benchmark but with consistent mean and median at 0.5 and a standard
deviation of 0.18.

Figure 1.c) shows the results for the CC index, which stand in stark contrast to

both the benchmark and A-F specifications for the same data and underlying
distribution of deprivation scores. The first thing to note is the far less granular
distribution, as counting ‘dimensions’ rather than summing indicator scores gives
only 5 increments of 0.2 between 0 and 1 on the scale. But most noticeably, the
distribution for the CC approach is hugely skewed and has resulting higher index
scores overall: a mean of 0.73 and a median of 0.8. It is worth repeating that these
results come from the same underlying set of observations and prevalence of
indicators. Simply said, the CC specification ‘exaggerates’ prevalence of multi-
dimensional poverty (which can be read as a headcount at any threshold score from
0.2 to 1) compared to the other indices. This finding confirms the discussion and
findings of Chakravarty and D’Ambrosio (2006), Rippin (2010) and others who
identified that ‘union approach’ results in ‘exaggeration’ of poverty. This is our first
finding from the laboratory work and is important for our second question: How do
the indices set robust baselines? The inherent characteristic of ‘exaggeration’ for CC
verses the other indices is a property that must be explicitly addressed when assessing
such baselines in practice.

Of course, we are mindful that particular specifications of A-F or CC Indices

may give different results. However, our detailed laboratory work suggests that
different iterations (weights or assignment of deprivations to dimensions)

do not alter

the fundamental findings of difference

, and the finding that CC exaggerates poverty at

all thresholds compared to the A-F and ‘sum count’ specification in any form.
Confirmatory results can be obtained from the authors.


background image

“Иқтисодиёт ва инновацион технологиялар” илмий электрон журнали. № 6, ноябрь-декабрь, 2017 йил

9

№ 6, 2017

www.iqtisodiyot.uz

Figure 1 Baseline Results

Monte Carlo Simulations (100 trials)

a)

‘Sum-Count’- Benchmark

b)

Alkire-Foster

c)

Categorical Counting

Properties of Index Scales

Values and Increments between 0 and 1 (indices all normalized to 1)

10 increments - each 0.1

18 increments – each 0.057

5 increments – each 0.2

Summary Statistical Properties

Mean

0.50

Mean

0.50

Mean

0.73

Median

0.50

Median

0.50

Median

0.80

Std Deviation

0.16

Std Deviation

0.18

Std Deviation

0.19

Skewness

0.00

Skewness

0.00

Skewness

-0.41

Kurtosis

2.80

Kurtosis

2.62

Kurtosis

2.81



№ 6, 2017

www.iqtisodiyot.uz


background image

“Иқтисодиёт ва инновацион технологиялар” илмий электрон журнали. № 6, ноябрь-декабрь, 2017 йил

10

№ 6, 2017

www.iqtisodiyot.uz

Tests for Sensitivity and Monotonicity

Our findings so far on the shape and properties of the different distributions

formed by indices also raise findings that are relevant to our second question for
poverty measurement:

How do indices indicate if poverty is changing over time to

meet SDG targets?

This is a key question for both accurately identifying difference

between sub-groups and for tracking change over time.

Figure 4 shows the results from Monte Carlo trials of repeated incremental

changes of plus and minus 10 percentage points for a randomly selected indicator
across all three indices. There are two main findings of interest: the level of change –
which will be affected by the weight of the indicator that is changed, and the
‘consistency’ of change for positive and negative values – symmetry. Figure 4 shows
that the Sum-Count index, with every indicator having a weight of 0.1, has a
symmetrical profile of change from 0.45 where indicator prevalence is zero, to 0.55
where indicator prevalence is 100%, from a starting point of 0.5. The A-F index has a
similar symmetrical profile but produces larger changes in index scores for the same
incremental change in indicator prevalence: from 0.42 overall if prevalence is
reduced to zero, and 0.58 overall if prevalence is increased to 100% from the same
starting point of 0.5. On the other hand, the CC index changes asymmetrically from
its much higher mean point of 0.72. Decreasing prevalence in one indicator reduces
the score by 0.04 points to 0.68, but increasing indicator prevalence to 100% raises
the score by 0.06 points, and the difference between these points is statistically
significant at 99% using t-tests. This suggests that the CC index is asymmetric.

Figure 2. Changes in Index Scores from Incremental

Change to Any Indicator

(100 Monte Carlo Trials)

Figure 3 shows the influence of differential weights in the A-F index. The

level of incremental change differs: large change is the result of higher indicator
weight, but changes similarly symmetric across incremental change to indicators of
differential weight.


background image

“Иқтисодиёт ва инновацион технологиялар” илмий электрон журнали. № 6, ноябрь-декабрь, 2017 йил

11

№ 6, 2017

www.iqtisodiyot.uz

Figure 3. A-F: Incremental Change in Indicator by Assigned Weight

(100 Monte Carlo trials)

When we attempt to replicated Figure 3 for the CC index, we are hindered by

the design of our laboratory data used to this point and the specific characteristics of
the index. Our laboratory data sets all indicator prevalence to 0.5, with random,
independent (non-correlated), indicators. This effects for the CC index because we
find saturation effects, which additionally prevent the index from increasing overall
scores from underlying increased prevalence.

Figure 4 shows the effects of saturation and the underlying patterns of

asymmetry that are seen in the CC index. same random assigned and non-correlated
lab data used at different levels of randomly assigned prevalence in order to account
for ‘saturation’ from our initial randomization that gave 0.72 as the mean starting
point. The results show clear asymmetry but with asymmetric attributes that differ
both by levels of saturation and by the ‘union assumption’ for the indicator of
incremental change. At low levels of saturation (20% random prevalence) the index
converges towards the 0%, while at high levels of saturation (80% random
prevalence) the index converges towards 100% prevalence. This overall asymmetry
is the result of differing asymmetry from the indicators according to their ‘union’
with other indicators. As expected, and by construction, the indicator that has no
other indicators in union (‘single union’), has clearest monotonic characteristics
across all levels of saturation. However, the indicators in union with one or two other
indicators clearly show differential slopes and very much small levels of incremental
change over all the ranges of incremental change of indicator, and become ‘flat’ at
high levels of concentration – where little if any change to the overall score from
incremental changes in indicator prevalence. These characteristics of asymmetry
operate across the implied differences in level of change that occur from the
indicator’s implied ‘weight’.


background image

“Иқтисодиёт ва инновацион технологиялар” илмий электрон журнали. № 6, ноябрь-декабрь, 2017 йил

12

№ 6, 2017

www.iqtisodiyot.uz

Figure 4. CC: Incremental Change in Indicator by Union Assumption with 20%,

50% and 80% random prevalence

(100 Monte Carlo Trials)


Testing the Effects of Correlation


So far we have relied on independent randomly assigned prevalence across our

10 hypothetical indicators; but, if we change our assumption of independence we can
assess if correlation between indicators affects the comparison of indices. The CC
index will inherently rely, in part, on linked probabilities for indicators that are
assessed in union. Such linked probabilities will not affect indicators that are not


background image

“Иқтисодиёт ва инновацион технологиялар” илмий электрон журнали. № 6, ноябрь-декабрь, 2017 йил

13

№ 6, 2017

www.iqtisodiyot.uz

aggregated in union – both for the Sum Count, A-F indices and for ‘single’ indicator
categorical dimensions in CC indices.

Figure 5 illustrates the effects of negative and positive correlation using the

‘union approach’ employed by CC indices.

Figure 5. Differential outcomes of Negative and Positive Correlation in Union

Aggregation

Figure 6 shows that positive and negative correlations produce inconsistent

arithmetic sums when the union aggregation approach is employed. The observed
prevalence of indicator A is 50% and B is 10% - with a negative correlation due to B
being populated in observations that are not populated by A. This leads to a 60%
combined union count. In the alternative case, C has 20% prevalence and is
positively correlated as both observations are common to observations that are also
deprived in A. The result of the union aggregation of A and C is 50%. This suggests
a fundamental measurement problem for monotonic index performance: as a change
to indicator prevalence will not produce increases to overall index score due to
positive and negative correlation differences.

To demonstrate the effect of correlation on index monotonicity we return to

using laboratory data and to do so, we reformulate our source data of 10,000
observations to drop the general assumption of independent randomly assigned
indicators and use correlation ratios between pairs or triads of indicators. To have
high levels of statistical certainty for our estimates we 100fixed intervals of the
correlation ratio, representing 2 percentage point increments between negative 100
and positive 100 percent. Using these data we test the relationship for linearity
between indicators using regression and are able to report results that have 0.01 p
values.

Figure 5 show two tests that assess how the level of correlation affects indices.

Figure 5a shows results for pairs and triads of indicators, and Figure 5b shows the
results of correlation of pairs on the overall index scores. We set the underlying
average indicator prevalence for the data to 50% prevalence for both these tests.


obs

A

B

Union

A & B

C

Union

A&C

1

2

x

x

x

x

3

x

x

x

x

4

5

x

x

x

6

-

x

x

7

x

x

x

8

x

x

x

9

10

50%

10%

60%

20%

50%

pos

iti

ve
c

orre

la

tion

ne
ga
tive
c

orre

la

tion


background image

“Иқтисодиёт ва инновацион технологиялар” илмий электрон журнали. № 6, ноябрь-декабрь, 2017 йил

14

№ 6, 2017

www.iqtisodiyot.uz

a)

On Mean Value of Pairs/Triads of Indicators

b)

On Index Scores from Correlation of Indicator Pairs

Figure 5. The Effect of Correlation on Multi-Dimensional Counting Indices

Figure 5a shows the effect of union aggregation of the mean value of pairs or

triads of indicators. The red line shows the changing mean of indicators that
aggregated using the union approach – either as pairs (twofold union) and triads
(threefold union). The blue line shows the mean for two or three indicators not
aggregated in union. We see that only indicators in union are affected by correlation,
and that differences in correlation are non-linear in their effect on the mean values of
those indicators. Figure 5b follows up on this finding to show the results of different
levels of correlation of pairs of indicators on overall index score across the three
indices, using the same pair of indicators used in Figure 5a as before at 50%
prevalence. We thus test to see how the indices react to positive correlation between
2 indicators out of all ten indicators. Figure 5b demonstrates how the CC index score
is influenced non-linearly by the level of correlation between those two indicators.
Neither A-F nor Sum Count indices are influenced by differing correlation levels
between that identical pair of indicators.

Out final test then takes these results and applies them to the three indices to

assess the effect of high correlation between the pair of indicators on differences in
indicator prevalence – the test for monotonicity that we used in the previous section.


background image

“Иқтисодиёт ва инновацион технологиялар” илмий электрон журнали. № 6, ноябрь-декабрь, 2017 йил

15

№ 6, 2017

www.iqtisodiyot.uz

Figure 6 shows the results. Correlation is seen to make CC method non-monotonic as
there is no change in index score from underlying changes to indicator prevalence
when indicators are subject to strong leading indicator correlation. This is not seen in
the Sum Count or AF index, for the same level or correlation for the same changes in
prevalence for such correlated indicators.

Figure 6. Changing Indicator Prevalence to High Correlation

Household Clustering, Age-Specific Censoring

We return to our original laboratory dataset of 10,000 observations and 10

randomly assigned independent ‘deprivations’ to consider the differences that occur
as a result of the two measurement problems we identified earlier when discussing
survey data and individual child level indices,

That indicators can be clustered at the household level while others are at the

individual level

That individual level indicators are age specific and any observation

(individual) not in that age range is missing and thus censored for that indicator

We take these two issues in term.
How do the original distributions described in Figure 1 change if some of the

indicators are at the household level and thus have the same value for all members of
that household? We reconfigure the laboratory dataset to assign individual
observations to ‘pseudo households’ randomly. We then regenerate the dataset with
the following approach:

We set the average number of observations per pseudo household as 3,

We allow up to a maximum of 7 observations to be allocated to a random

household.

To this new distribution, 2 indicators were assigned to be household level

indicators, the remaining 8 indicators remain at the individual level and are thus not
‘clustered’.


background image

“Иқтисодиёт ва инновацион технологиялар” илмий электрон журнали. № 6, ноябрь-декабрь, 2017 йил

16

№ 6, 2017

www.iqtisodiyot.uz

These assumptions are designed to illustrate the potential effects of household

clustering compared to a random allocation and are not intended to be representative
of actual household formation and size. We tested other specifications and found that
our findings on index reaction to clustering was unchanged in nature.

The results are shown in Figure 7. Household clustering increases the

skewness of all three distributions compared to their baselines in Figure 1, but the
degree and effect of skew varies by index. The CC index increases skew most and
increases its mean score from 0.73 to 0.82. Household clustering thus seems to
increase the potential of the CC index to ‘saturate’ as desicussed earlier. On the other
hand, the Sum Count and A-F indices are leaner functions, and the inclusion
household level observations produces an upward shift of poverty line as individually
differing indicators are replaced with repeated household level versions. The mean
score rises from 0.50 to 0.57 for the benchmark, but from 0.50 to 0.54 for A-F, a
reflection that, on average, lower weighted indicators were affected. This raises the
possibility that A-F type differential weights could be used to address household
clustering effects on individual level indices. We return to this point later in
discussion.

But our test on the impact of household clustering of 2 out of 10 indicators is

not indicative of what happens in practice with child poverty indices, where we see
that household level indicators are a much higher proportion of all indicators – often
six and sometimes eight out of ten indicators are at the household level (Gordon et al
2003, de Neuburgh et al 2013).


background image

“Иқтисодиёт ва инновацион технологиялар” илмий электрон журнали. № 6, ноябрь-декабрь, 2017 йил

17

№ 6, 2017

www.iqtisodiyot.uz

a)

Sum-Count Benchmark

b)

A-F

3

c)

CC

4

Summary Statistical Properties & Differences from Baseline

Revised Statistic

Difference from Baseline

Revised Statistic

Difference from

Baseline

Revised Statistic

Difference from

Baseline

Mean

0.57

+0.07 **

Mean

0.54

+0.04 **

Mean

0.82

+0.09 **

Median

0.60

+0.10

Median

0.56

+0.06

Median 0.8

0

Std Deviation

0.15

-0.01 n.s.

Std Deviation

0.18

-0.002 n.s.

Std Deviation

0.170

-0.022 n.s.

Skewness

-0.06

Skewness

-0.01

Skewness

-0.68

Kurtosis

2.83

Kurtosis

2.61

Kurtosis

3.03

Figure 7

Revised results allowing for Household Clustering (2/10 indicators at household level)

Monte Carlo Simulations (100 trials)

Notes: ** significant at 1% using two tailed t-test


The results from alternative allocation of household level indicators to dimensions are available from the authors but do not
alter interpretation of results from this example

3

Dimension 1(I;I), Dimension 2(I;I) and Dimension 3(I;I;I; I;HH;HH) (HH= household level indicator)

4

Dimension 1(I;I) Dimension 2(I;I), Dimension 3(I;I), Dimension 4(I; I;HH) and Dimension 5(HH)

№ 6, 2017

www.iqtisodiyot.uz


background image

“Иқтисодиёт ва инновацион технологиялар” илмий электрон журнали. № 6, ноябрь-декабрь, 2017 йил

18

№ 6, 2017

www.iqtisodiyot.uz

Table 1

Household Clustering at Higher Margin (6/10 indicators household level)

Sum-Count

A-F

5

CC

6

Mean

0.69

0.66

0.93

Median

0.7

0.67

1

Standard
deviation

0.14

0.16

0.13

Skewness

-0.52

-0.34

-1.82

Kurtosis

3.45

3.19

6.41

Table 1 gives an indication of the additional difference that would from such

higher levels of household clustering – with 6 out of 10 indicatorts at the household
level. The CC index’s saturation is now clear, with mean at 0.93 and median at 1.
These results suggest a clear caveat for using indices of this type in contexts with
high levels of deprivation and high proportion of indicators at household level. On
the other hand, A-F under these same assumptions maintains its lower means and
medians and skewness compared to the sum-count benchmark, another indication that
differential indicator weighting for household level variables is worth considering in
applied index work.

We now turn to look at age specific censoring of individual level indicators and

its potential impact on results from our first set of randomly assigned laboratory data.
By definition only individual level variables can be age-specific. If individual level
indicators are censored the ratio of observed individual level variance falls relative to
common individual indicators and to the household level repeated values in any
index. As a result the potential for the dominance from clustered household level
variables rises for any index. To capture this effect we further transform the
household clustered version of our laboratory dataset that was seen in Figure 7. This
allows us to consider the cumulative and marginal changes from censored data
alongside clustered data. We censor prevalence for a

single indicator

from 10,000

to 7,100 to illustrate the underlying population size of the 0-4 year old population in
the three countries (UNDESA 2015) that we consider later in Part 2. To do this we
replace all postive 1 values to zero for these 2,900 cases. While in reality, these
values would be ‘missing’, we chose to replace with zeros to avoid the need to
additionally re-weight to adjust to underlying population differences. However, in
applied use of indices, population reweighting would require more consideration and
we discuss this issue later below.

Figure 8 gives the revised results for this transformation and its effect on the

indices. We show the net change in summary statistics compared to those seen from
household clustering alone in Figure 7. The results show histograms for the
benchmark and AF-MPI have flattened curves around mean values. For the sum-
count benchmark this leads to a small but statistically significant (at 1%) reduction to
the mean compared to the Figure 7 results.

5

Dimension1(I;HH), Dimension 2(I;HH) and Dimension 3(I;I;HH; HH;HH;HH)

6

Dimension 1(I;HH) Dimension 2(I;HH), Dimension 3(I;HH), Dimension 4(I; HH;HH) and Dimension 5(HH)


background image

“Иқтисодиёт ва инновацион технологиялар” илмий электрон журнали. № 6, ноябрь-декабрь, 2017 йил

19

№ 6, 2017

www.iqtisodiyot.uz

Multiple Deprivation- Benchmark

A-F

CC

Summary Statistical Properties & Differences from Iteration shown in Figure 7

Revised Statistic

Difference from

Figure 5

Revised Statistic

Difference from

Figure 5

Revised Statistic

Difference from

Figure 5

Mean

0.55

-0.025 **

Mean

0.58

0.039 **

Mean

0.79

-0.025 **

Median

0.52

-0.082

Median

0.58

0.0272

Median

0.8

0

Std Deviation

0.15

-0.002 n.s.

Std Deviation

0.16

-0.023 n.s.

Std Deviation

0.18

0.005 n.s.

Skewness -0.04

-0.17

-0.56

Kurtosis 2.84

2.97

2.90

Figure 8. Results allowing for Household Clustering and Age-Specific Incidence of Deprivation

Monte Carlo Simulations (100 trials)

Notes: ** significant at 1% using two tailed t-test

The results from alternative allocation of household level indicators to dimensions are available from the authors but do

not alter interpretation of results from this example

№ 6, 2017

www.iqtisodiyot.uz


background image

“Иқтисодиёт ва инновацион технологиялар” илмий электрон журнали. № 6, ноябрь-декабрь, 2017 йил

20

№ 6, 2017

www.iqtisodiyot.uz

For A-F there is a small statistically significant increase (at 1%) in the mean.

Both these specifications show reduced standard deviations that result from fewer
positive values for indicators. The CC specification shows a small significant (at 1%)
decrease in mean score and an increased in standard deviation. However, underlying
skewness measures have risen to the highest level across all three simulations across
Figure 1, 7 and 8. These results show the CC index reacts differently to changes in
individual level prevalence compared to the Sum Count and A-F indices and this will
further contribute to problems of monotonicity

We now turn to a final consideration of the potential effects of clustering and

censoring by looking at potential effects on correlation. For individual child level
indices, the issue of correlation is obviously partly determined by what is common to
all children in a household and what is particular to children of certain age. How
does clustering and censoring affect the assessment of indicator correlation, and how
can our indices minimize the effects of correlation bias.

Figure 9. Correlation Tests and Clustered and Censored Indicators

In Figure 9 we visually demonstrate how an assessment of correlation is

affected by clustering and censoring. We show hypothetical data (not randomly
assigned) from the first 5 households of a hypothetical dataset with 10 indicators.
The results reflect tetrachoric correlation tests in accordance with the binary ordinal
data in these indices. The first correlation matrix shows the results for the original
data as a baseline. The second matrix shows the comparison with the first matrix and
thus the effect on the correlation ratios of censoring those data shown in blue in the

hhd

person

a

b

c

d

e

f

g

h

i

j

1

1

1

0

1

1

0

0

0

0

0

1

1

2

0

0

1

0

0

0

0

1

0

0

1

3

0

0

0

1

0

0

0

0

1

0

Effects on Correlation Ratios

1

4

0

1

1

1

0

0

1

1

0

0

2

1

1

1

1

1

0

1

1

1

1

0

Changes sign when censored changes from zero to missing

3

1

0

0

0

0

1

0

0

0

0

0

3

2

1

1

1

0

1

0

1

1

0

1

Changes sign when household variables rewieghted

4

1

0

1

0

1

0

1

0

0

1

0

4

2

1

0

1

1

0

0

0

1

0

0

Changes sign when both adustments made

5

1

0

0

0

0

1

1

0

0

0

0

5

2

0

1

0

0

0

0

1

0

1

0

5

3

0

0

0

0

0

1

1

1

1

1

i) Baseline - No adjustment

ii) Adjustment for censoring (0 values changed to missing in blue cells above)

a

b

c

d

e

f

g

h

i

j

a

b

c

d

e

f

g

h

i

j

a

1

a

1

b

0.151

1

b

-0.210

1

c

1

0.168

1

c

1 -0.327

1

d

0.647

0.270

0.649

1

d

1 0.293 0.777

1

e

-0.034 -0.352 -0.171

-1

1

e

-1

-1

-1

-1

1

f

-0.537 -0.157 -0.651

0.011 -0.006

1

f

-0.210 0.293 -0.327 0.293

-1

1

g

0.091

0.687

0.100 -0.541 -0.408 -0.057

1

g

-0.284 0.424 -0.401 -0.746

-1 0.424

1

h

0.826 -0.157

0.893

0.200 -0.408 -0.057

0.619

1

h

1 -0.746

1 0.182

-1 0.424 0.307

1

i

-0.582

0.628 -0.695

0.130

-1

0.551

0.692 -0.139

1

i

-0.641

1 -0.754 -0.135

-1

1

1 -0.320

1

j

0.346 -0.195

0.213 -0.577

0.043

0.196

0.785

0.785

0.139

1

j

-1

-1

-1

-1

-1

1

1

1

1

1

iii) Adjustment for clustering (1/n) for household clustered variables in green cells above)

iv) Both Adjustments: ii) and iii) compared to i)

a

b

c

d

e

f

g

h

i

j

a

b

c

d

e

f

g

h

i

j

a

1

a

1

b

-1

1

b

-1

1

c

1

-1

1

c

1

-1

1

d

1

-1

1

1

d

1

-1

1

1

e

-1

1

-1

-1

1

e

-1

1

-1

-1

1

f

-1

-1

-1

0

0

1

f

-1

-1

-1 0.144 -0.144

1

g

-0.544

-1 -0.544 -0.601 0.601 0.121

1

g

-1

-1

-1 -0.814 0.814

1

1

h

0.336

-1 0.336 0.293 -0.293 -0.091 0.619

1

h

-0.052

-1 -0.052 0.307 -0.31 0.503 0.307

1

i

-0.475

-1 -0.475 0.037 -0.037 0.765 0.692 -0.139

1

i

-1

-1

-1 -0.320 0.320 0.773

1 -0.320

1

j

-0.253

1 -0.253 -0.616 0.616 -0.346 0.785 0.785 0.139

1

j

-1

1

-1

-1

1

1

1

1

1

1


background image

“Иқтисодиёт ва инновацион технологиялар” илмий электрон журнали. № 6, ноябрь-декабрь, 2017 йил

21

№ 6, 2017

www.iqtisodiyot.uz

original matrix, representing values originally designated as ‘zeros’ but changed to
missing values. The effect of this adjustment is to change the sign of correlation
ratios in 9 instances shaded blue. The third matrix shows the results of re-weighting
the values of clustered household level indicators, using a simple per-capita approach
(for a household with 4 observations we ‘reweight’ the indicator value from 1 to 0.25
(¼), and so on). Again, this adjustment changes the sign of correlation ratio in 13
cases, shaded green. The fourth and final matrix uses both adjustments and the
resulting changes in sign for the correlations are confirmed in 15 cells highlighted
orange. This test and designed to visually show the potential of censoring and
clustering on correlation ratios and is illustrative only; the small samples in our
demonstration mean that we put no weight at all on the changes of value of
correlation ratios or on the robustness of changes in sign, but actual survey data of
significant sample size would show similar changes to the size and sign of correlation
ratios.

What effects will these changes in correlation from controlling for clustering

and censoring have on the indices? The changes in sign that come from censoring
and clustering adjustments mean that CC indices will be at most risk of resulting bias,
as we have seen how different signs of correlation between indicators have the ability
to alter monotonicity most in that index. But CC indices, due to their axiomatic
normative adoption of ‘rights based’ equal weights, prevents changing index
weighting assumptions to empirically reflect effects of clustering or censoring. The
practice for these indices is not consistent, but the more recent MODA approach (de
Neuburgh et al 2013) has produced different indices for age-specific sub-group of
children unlike earlier CC approaches (Gordon et al 2003, UNICEF/CEPAL 2009).
On the other hand, A-F approaches are more adaptable to empirically derived
indicator weights to adjust for over and under-representation of indicators. But the
use of frequency weights to adjust for censoring needs to be better addressed across
all types of indicators, as suggested in the review of global MPI (Klasen & Dotter
2014, Kovacevic and Calderon 2015).

Part 2: Indices using Household Survey Data

In the second part of our analysis we test some of the key findings from the

laboratory work with real survey data. At this point it is crucial to restate that this
work will NOT replicate actual indices that are in place. We test underlying
methodologies not compare ‘branded indices’ of different forms such as MPI,
MODA or others.

We use harmonized survey data prepared by Professor D. Gordon and his team

at University of Bristol using DHS and MICS surveys. This ensures that consistent
approaches to indicator specification and data cleaning have been used across all the
different national datasets. Our data comes from three DHS surveys in 2010 for
Colombia, Bangladesh and Tanzania. To avoid some of the problems of age-specific
censoring and in the interests of space and concision, we limit our indices to the
population aged less than five years old. We take 10 indicators and construct three
indices from those indicators:


background image

“Иқтисодиёт ва инновацион технологиялар” илмий электрон журнали. № 6, ноябрь-декабрь, 2017 йил

22

№ 6, 2017

www.iqtisodiyot.uz

the ‘sum-count’ benchmark index.

A-F: we have 3 dimensions (2, 3 and 5 indicators per dimension)

CC: 5 dimensions (2, 3,1,1,3 indicators per dimension)

Table 2

Indicators, Dimensions and Weights for Test Indices

Categorical Counting: Composition of Dimensions

Nutrition

(1/5)

Infant feeding Wasting

Health

(1/5)

DPT all

Unskilled
birth
attendant

Child
mortality

Water

(1/5)

Drinking
water

Sanitation

(1/5)

Toilet type

Housing &
Living Standards

(1/5)

Overcrowding Wealth low

quintile

Info devices

AF method: Composition of Dimensions

Nutrition

(1/3)

Infant feeding
(1/6)

Wasting
(1/6)

Health

(1/3)

DPT all
(1/9)

Unskilled
birth
attendant
(1/9)

Child
mortality
(1/9)

Living
Standards

(1/3)

Drinking water
(1/15)

Toilet type
(1/15)

Overcrowding
(1/15)

Wealth
poorest
quintile
(1/15)

Lack of
Information
Devices
(1/15)

Our indices are not designed to be relevant or to be inherently robust or

meaningful in themselves because our motivation is not to design and test an optimal
index. We do not test our set of indicators for their suitability, reliability, validity or
underlying robustness in their performance for any overall index specification
because we are not interested in how these indices accurately assess multi-
dimensional poverty for this test, merely in their comparative performance according
to underlying measurement properties. Our choice of indicators is also dictated by
the need NOT to approximate to an actual index in place. We have chosen some
indicators that are used in multi-dimensional indicators, and others, such as ‘lowest
quintile of wealth index’ that are not, and perhaps, never should be.

Figure 10 shows the key results for each of the three indices in each of the

three countries and we limit reporting of results to simple comparison of means and
maxima in order to establish whether the lab results of ‘exaggeration’ of poverty we
saw earlier continue to be seen between CC and the other indices using actual survey
data. The Sum Count and A-F indices all provide similar mean headcounts and
similar maxima – using these combination of deprivations, the maximum score is 0.8
across all countries for the ‘sum-count’ index and 0.87 for A-F. However, the CC
index gives consistently higher mean scores compared to the other indices – in the
region of 50 per cent higher. Additionally, the maximum score for CC is always 1.00,


background image

“Иқтисодиёт ва инновацион технологиялар” илмий электрон журнали. № 6, ноябрь-декабрь, 2017 йил

23

№ 6, 2017

www.iqtisodiyot.uz

representing the outcome from counting ‘dimensions’, or headings of deprivation,
rather than sums of the underlying deprivation indicators. These findings support the
earlier laboratory work on both cardinal and scalar properties and confirm the
findings of ‘exaggeration’ for CC indices verses A-F and the Sum Count’.

How do the indices perform when considering monotonicity? We show tests

for two indicators: water and the presence of skilled birth attendant. We have chosen
these as they reflect the marginal cases and are illustrative of the underlying
measurement properties we examined in the laboratory data

water is a household level variable that has a great implicit weight in CC as

it is a single variable dimension, but has lower implicit weight in the other indices.

Presence of an unskilled birth attendant is an individual level variable that has

low implicit weight in CC as it is in a union of three indicators in a single dimension,
whereas in the other indices it is measured using its indicator prevalence with slightly
differing weights.

Figure 10. Headline Results for Indices in Three Counties: distributions, means

and maximum values


background image

“Иқтисодиёт ва инновацион технологиялар” илмий электрон журнали. № 6, ноябрь-декабрь, 2017 йил

24

№ 6, 2017

www.iqtisodiyot.uz


TANZANIA

BANGLADESH

COLOMBIA

Water

Presence of Skilled Attendant at Birth

Figure 11. Sensitivity Tests for Water and Presence of Skilled Birth Attendant Indicators

№ 6, 2017

www.iqtisodiyot.uz


background image

“Иқтисодиёт ва инновацион технологиялар” илмий электрон журнали. № 6, ноябрь-декабрь, 2017 йил

25

№ 6, 2017

www.iqtisodiyot.uz

Figure 11 shows common results across indices and across countries in the

changes to both indicators from incremental changes in prevalence. Incremental
changes to prevalence of the water indicator has big impact on the CC index across
all countries, as represented by its status in a single variable dimension. The change
in overall slope from zero to 100% prevalence is much steeper when compared to the
sum-count and A-F and the absolute changes in index values are far higher overall.
On the other hand, changes to the prevalence of the ‘skilled birth attendant’ has little,
if any, discernable change to CC index – as shown by the ‘flat line’ in Figure 11, but
for the other indices, changed prevalence is clearly associated with increased or
decreased incremental index scores. These results confirm what we saw in the
monotonicity tests for the laboratory data, but are more clearly interpretable for
applied poverty measurement and for planning poverty reduction. Investments in
service provision could either see huge or no credit given in changing poverty indices
using the CC method.

Table 3

Tanzania: Regional Ranking for Multi-dimensional Poverty Index Scores

Multi-dimensionally Poor Children aged under 5

Difference in 3 Ranking Places Shaded


background image

“Иқтисодиёт ва инновацион технологиялар” илмий электрон журнали. № 6, ноябрь-декабрь, 2017 йил

26

№ 6, 2017

www.iqtisodiyot.uz

However, the importance of real world, applied implications of measurement

properties can be further illustrated with real survey data and we consider a single
further instance of potential importance: the identification of differences and poverty
rankings for sub-groups, of the population. We restrict our illustrative example to
regional differences in poverty, and regional rankings by poverty in Tanzania. A
fuller set of results is available from the authors. Table 3 shows the regional rankings
for Tanzania, where there are 26 sub-national regions/provinces. We calculate the
headcount mean score for each index at this level and then compare all three indices,
using the ‘sum count’ index as the baseline. Where poverty rankings differ by

3

places or more

from the sum count index we highlight in orange. A-F produces three

regions with ranking difference of 3 or more places, while CC produces higher levels
of ranking difference, 13 or one-half of all regions. These results suggest that the use
of MD poverty indices to regionally assess needs and allocate funds based on multi-
dimensional poverty levels would potentially face huge uncertainty, especially when
compared to the simple ‘sum count’ approach.

Findings and Conclusions

Findings

We have considered the performance of two methodologies to multi-

dimensional poverty counting indices and compared them to a simpler ‘Sum-Count’
as a benchmark. We have done so with three main questions in mind for monitoring
SDG poverty goals and targets.

How do the indices compare in their cardinal and scalar properties?

This is

at heart a rather academic question but has huge consequences for poverty
measurement and thus to applied target and policy monitoring. We found that using
10 indicators A-F produced distributions that were normal but more granular. The
number of increments in the scale depends on the differential weights but would be a
minimum of 10. CC is a lot less granular because dimensions (categories) and not
indicators are summed/counted but would always be less than 10 for that number of
indicators. This has real repercussions for how poverty is interpreted because the
underlying arithmetic link to the indicators of each deprivation is different between
indices. A counting of categories (effectively headings under which deprivations are
placed) produces a categorical ordinal variable which, of course, can be counted but
interpreting the sum as a cardinal number needs a lot of care. A-F sums indicator
weights and the index score is resultantly more cardinal in nature. But for both
indices a score may not reflect more or less deprivation: it is possible for two children
to differ in index scores for the same number of deprivations across both indices.
However, it is noticeable that good practice in MPI reporting often contains ‘censored
headcounts’ for comparison (see Alkire et al 2017 for example).

A-F index scores can always be decomposed back to indicator prevalence but

CC cannot because dimensions are not derived by arithmetic sums but by Boolean
aggregation: an indicator in any dimension may or may not count depending on how
many other indicators it is in ‘union’ with. Practice in CC has established non-
consistent aggregation between dimensions, making arithmetic attribution at the
indicator level very problematic.


background image

“Иқтисодиёт ва инновацион технологиялар” илмий электрон журнали. № 6, ноябрь-декабрь, 2017 йил

27

№ 6, 2017

www.iqtisodiyot.uz

Our laboratory testing also showed that CC indices tended to saturate easily:

this means that arithmetic changes to the sum of dimensions is probably not
consistent as the index changes to reflect higher prevalence of deprivation and/or
correlation between indicators of deprivation.

These properties lead us to consider the second question:

How do they set

robust baselines?

Our analysis confirmed the theoretical literature’s findings that

‘union’ approach produces ‘exaggeration’ affected the CC approach: mean scores
were higher by a factor of around 50 per cent across both laboratory and real survey
data examples. We do not suggest that the count of dimensions is not accurate, but
that it skews the underlying prevalence of multiple deprivation upwards. We saw that
no child was poor in every one of 10 deprivations in three countries, but that children
we always found to be poor under every heading. Perhaps, the term ‘reliability’ is
more useful than robustness, but conclusions from this finding are for applied policy
measurement at the national level to take forward.

Finally, our third question, “

How do they asses if poverty is changing over time

to meet SDG targets?”

We found big differences between the indices in capturing

change from underlying changes in indicator prevalence. Weights mattered and
produced different levels of change according to the assigned indicator weight in A-
F, but we also saw surprisingly different ‘implicit’ dimension weights in what were
normatively assigned ‘equal weights’ in CC index, reflecting the combination of
household level indicators and ‘union’ properties. But differential weighting in A-F
was always seen to be symmetric and consistent: levels of change consistently
reflected the arithmetic values assigned to the indicator as prevalence rose or fell.
This was not so for CC index where the underlying logic of Boolean union approach
produced a range of cumulative effects. First, the same arithmetic property of
exaggeration as discussed above produces and over-representation of the likelihood
of a move from zero to one when compared to a move from one to zero, especially in
dimensions that have more than one indicator which are the majority of dimensions in
observed practice. Second, that property of asymmetry was mediated by saturation,
making non-consistent asymmetry an axiomatic property of the index. Third,
correlation matters hugely for indicators held in union for CC – a specific
measurement property above and beyond the issue of overall correlation between
indicators for all indices. Correlation within dimension leads to inconsistent changes
to overall index score from changes in indicator prevalence.

How are these indices affected by the data properties of household clustering

and age-specific censoring? Both increased the relative skewness of CC – increasing
the probability of saturation, exaggeration and non-monotonicity.

Discussion

Our approach strengthens the case for using the simple ‘sum-count’ version of

a set of indicators alongside indices when comparing them. Indeed, we would
strongly suggest that this be a simple ‘sensitivity and robustness’ exercise when
testing indices before they are adopted for measurement purposes.

We directly considered the impact of household clustering and age-specific

censoring in the laboratory but not in the analysis of the three national datasets. One
reason for this was insufficient space and time, and thus we have left some issues for


background image

“Иқтисодиёт ва инновацион технологиялар” илмий электрон журнали. № 6, ноябрь-декабрь, 2017 йил

28

№ 6, 2017

www.iqtisodiyot.uz

future work. But another constraint was tackling the issue of population weights,
which would be required for adjusting differences from age-specific censoring. The
issue of population reweighting deserves a paper on its own and was not collapsible
to cover here in any depth. But one early finding in the laboratory does suggest that
‘differential indicator weights’, as per A-F, could be used to counter some of the
effects of household clustering. This needs to be considered further, and would mean
a departure from practice in which equal weighting was normatively assigned. The
issue would be how far replacing ‘equal weights’ with empirical assumptions makes
better child level indices at the expense of complexity and transparency and thus spoil
the ‘easy sell’ to policy makers.

But the future to some of the solutions to household clustering and age-specific

censoring is through better data. MICS and DHS programmes are not designed to
make multi-dimensional indices, but SDG targets now exist for larger age-ranges of
children and for more individual level targets. This could eventually lead to the
creation of ‘suites’ of indicators that could create dimensions across all ages of
children – for instance, considering ‘cognitive development’ and other measures of
non-cognitive performance for pre-school aged children that could allow ‘learning’ or
some other higher level ‘dimension’ to replace the crudely determined ‘education’
dimensions that already exist. The example of ensuring no age-censoring in most of
Bhutan’s child MPI (Alkire et al 2016) is a clear pointer on how to bring together
different indicators to cover all children of all ages consistently. This was a
methodological solution to a measurement problem that was not overly constrained
by fixed normative labels for dimensions, a clear indication of pragmatic ways
forward. Other issues for survey data are indicators or material deprivation – in these
or other surveys. Better individual age-related population weights in survey data is
also a clear need for the future.

But finally, we must emphasise our acknowledgement that national preferences

for methodological approaches to poverty measurement are at the heart of SDG
poverty reduction. We have emphasized empirical measurement principles but an
alternative preference for counting ‘rights’ or categories of poverty should also be
acknowledged and respected. For poverty statisticians facing this choice, the need is
to ensure that such preferences are accompanied by transparent knowledge of and
acceptance of the outcomes of choosing a methodology. The empirical and
measurement consequences of that choice are what we have tried, in part, to outline
here.

But it is always the case that you can attribute multi-dimensional poverty to

breaches of rights through a decomposition of an index rather than in its formulation

.

Our findings suggest that the measurement of poverty through CC of rights does not
allow the opposite to be true. Thus the trade-off is not binary but the good news is
that it is possible to have a rights compliant index from DHS and MICS surveys that
answers all our 3 questions for SDG monitoring.

Bibliography

1.

Alkire S (2014) Measuring Acute Poverty in the Developing World:

Robustness and Scope of the Multidimensional Poverty Index,

World Development

Vol 59, July 2014, Pages 251-274


background image

“Иқтисодиёт ва инновацион технологиялар” илмий электрон журнали. № 6, ноябрь-декабрь, 2017 йил

29

№ 6, 2017

www.iqtisodiyot.uz

2.

Alkire S and Foster J (2011) Counting and Multidimensional Poverty

Measurement,

Journal of Public Economics

, 95(7-8) 476-87

3.

Alkire S., Foster J., Seth S., Santos M-E., Roche J-M., Ballón P (eds) (2015)

Multidimensional Poverty Measurement and Analysis

, Oxford, Oxford University

Press

4.

Alkire S., Dorji L., Gyeltshen S. and Minten T (2016)

Child Poverty in

Bhutan: Insights from Multidimensional Child Poverty Index and Qualitative
Interviews with Poor Children

, Thimphu, Bhutan National Statistics Bureau.

5.

CEPAL (2013),

Panorama Social 2013

. Santiago de Chile: CEPAL.

6.

CEPAL/UNICEF (2010)

Pobreza infantil en América Latina y el Caribe

. ,

Fondo de las Naciones Unidas para la Infancia, Comisión Económica para América
Latina

y

el

Caribe,

Publicación

de

las

Naciones

Unidas,

https://www.unicef.org/honduras/Pobreza_infantil_America_Latina_Caribe_2010.pdf

.

7.

Chakravarty and D’Ambrosio (2006) The measurement of social exclusion,

Review of Income and Wealth

52(3), 377-398

8.

Commission on Global Poverty (2016)

Monitoring Global Poverty:

Report of the Commission on Global Poverty

, Washington DC: International Bank

for Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank.

9.

Dotter C. and Klasen S. (2014)

The Multidimensional Poverty Index:

Achievements, Conceptual and Empirical Issues

, New York, UNDP

10.

http://hdr.undp.org/en/content/multidimensional-poverty-index-

achievements-conceptual-and-empirical-issues

11.

Eurostat (2015)

Being Young in Europe Today: Living Conditions

,

Luxembourg: Eurostat

12.

Gordon D., Nandy S., Pantazis C., Permberton S., and Townsend P (2003)

Child Poverty in the Developing World

, Bristol: Policy Press

13.

Hancioglu A, Arnold F (2013) Coverage in MNCH: Tracking Progress in

Health for Women and Children Using DHS and MICS Household Surveys.

PLoS

Med

10(5): e1001391. doi:10.1371/journal.pmed.1001391

14.

Kovasevic M and Calderon C (2014) UNDP’s Multidimensional Poverty

Index:

2014

Specifications,

New

York:

UNDP

HDRO

http://hdr.undp.org/en/content/undp%E2%80%99s-multidimensional-poverty-index-
2014-specifications

15.

Klasen S and Lahoti R (2016)

How Serious is the Neglect of Intra-

Household Inequality in Multi-Dimensional Poverty Indices?

Courant Center

Discussion paper 200, Göttingen, Georg-August-Universität Göttingen.

16.

MOLISA (2016)

Multidimensional Poverty in Vietnam

, Hanoi: Ministry of

Labour, Invalids and Social Affairs

17.

Ravallion M (2011) On multidimensional indices of poverty,

The Journal

of Economic Inequality

, Vol 9, Issue 2, pp 235–248

18.

Rippin N (2010)

Poverty Severity in a Multidimensional Framework: The

Issue of Inequality between Dimensions

, Courant Center Discussion Paper 47,

Göttingen, Georg-August-Universität Göttingen.


background image

“Иқтисодиёт ва инновацион технологиялар” илмий электрон журнали. № 6, ноябрь-декабрь, 2017 йил

30

№ 6, 2017

www.iqtisodiyot.uz

19.

Roche J M (2013) Monitoring progress in child poverty reduction:

methodological insights and illustration to the case study of Bangladesh‘,

Journal of

Social Indicators Research

, Vol 112, Issue 2, pp 363-390

20.

UNDP (2010)

The Real Wealth of Nations: Pathways to Human

Development

, Human Development Report 2010, New York: United Nations

Development Programme

Библиографические ссылки

Alkire S (2014) Measuring Acute Poverty in the Developing World: Robustness and Scope of the Multidimensional Poverty Index, World Development Vol 59, July 2014, Pages 251-274

Alkire S and Foster J (2011) Counting and Multidimensional Poverty Measurement, Journal of Public Economics, 95(7-8) 476-87

Alkire S., Foster J., Seth S., Santos M-E., Roche J-M., Ballon P (eds) (2015) Multidimensional Poverty Measurement and Analysis, Oxford, Oxford University Press

Alkire S., Doiji L., Gycltshcn S. and Mintcn T (2016) Child Poverty in Bhutan: Insights from Multidimensional Child Poverty Index and Qualitative Interviews with Poor Children, Thimphu, Bhutan National Statistics Bureau.

CEPAL (2013), Panorama Social 2013. Santiago de Chile: CEPAL.

CEPAL/UNICEF (2010) Pobreza infantil en America Latina у el Caribe. , Fondo de las Naciones Unidas para la Infancia, Comision Economica para America Latina у el Caribe, Publicacion de las Naciones Unidas, https://www.uniccf.or<’ honduras/Pobreza infantil America Latina Caribe 2010.pdf

Chakravarty and D' Ambrosio (2006) The measurement of social exclusion, Review of Income and Wealth 52(3), 377-398

Commission on Global Poverty (2016) Monitoring Global Poverty: Report of the Commission on Global Poverty, Washington DC: International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank.

Dotter C. and Klasen S. (2014) The Multidimensional Poverty Index: Achievements, Conceptual and Empirical Issues, New York, UNDP

http://hdr.undp.org/en/content/multidimensional-DQvertv-index-achievements-conceptual-and-empirical-issues

Eurostat (2015) Being Young in Europe Today: Living Conditions, Luxembourg: Eurostat

Gordon D., Nandy S., Pantazis C., Permberton S., and Townsend P (2003) Child Poverty in the Developing World, Bristol: Policy Press

Hancioglu A, Arnold F (2013) Coverage in MNCH: Tracking Progress in Health for Women and Children Using DHS and MICS Household Surveys. PLoS Med 10(5): e 1001391. doi: 10.1371/joumal.pmed. 1001391

Kovasevic M and Calderon C (2014) UNDP’s Multidimensional Poverty

Index: 2014 Specifications, New York: UNDP HDRO

http://hdr.undp.org/en/content/undp%E2%80%99s-multidimensional-povertv-index-2014-specifications

Klascn S and Lahoti R (2016) How Serious is the Neglect of IntraHousehold Inequality in Multi-Dimensional Poverty Indices? Courant Center Discussion paper 200, Gottingen, Georg-August-Universitat Gottingen.

MOLISA (2016) Multidimensional Poverty in Vietnam, Hanoi: Ministry of Labour, Invalids and Social Affairs

Ravallion M (2011) On multidimensional indices of poverty. The Journal of Economic Inequality’, Vol 9, Issue 2, pp 235-248

Rippin N (2010) Poverty Severity in a Multidimensional Framework: The Issue of Inequality between Dimensions, Courant Center Discussion Paper 47, Gottingen, Gcorg-August-Univcrsitat Gottingen.

Roche J M (2013) Monitoring progress in child poverty reduction: methodological insights and illustration to the case study of Bangladesh1, Journal of Social Indicators Research, Vol 112, Issue 2, pp 363-390

UNDP (2010) The Rea! Wealth of Nations: Pathways to Human Development, Human Development Report 2010, New York: United Nations Development Programme

inLibrary — это научная электронная библиотека inConference - научно-практические конференции inScience - Журнал Общество и инновации UACD - Антикоррупционный дайджест Узбекистана UZDA - Ассоциации стоматологов Узбекистана АСТ - Архитектура, строительство, транспорт Open Journal System - Престиж вашего журнала в международных базах данных inDesigner - Разработка сайта - создание сайтов под ключ в веб студии Iqtisodiy taraqqiyot va tahlil - ilmiy elektron jurnali yuridik va jismoniy shaxslarning in-Academy - Innovative Academy RSC MENC LEGIS - Адвокатское бюро SPORT-SCIENCE - Актуальные проблемы спортивной науки GLOTEC - Внедрение цифровых технологий в организации MuviPoisk - Смотрите фильмы онлайн, большая коллекция, новинки кинопроката Megatorg - Доска объявлений Megatorg.net: сайт бесплатных частных объявлений Skinormil - Космецевтика активного действия Pils - Мультибрендовый онлайн шоп METAMED - Фармацевтическая компания с полным спектром услуг Dexaflu - от симптомов гриппа и простуды SMARTY - Увеличение продаж вашей компании ELECARS - Электромобили в Ташкенте, Узбекистане CHINA MOTORS - Купи автомобиль своей мечты! PROKAT24 - Прокат и аренда строительных инструментов